RISS 학술연구정보서비스

검색
다국어 입력

http://chineseinput.net/에서 pinyin(병음)방식으로 중국어를 변환할 수 있습니다.

변환된 중국어를 복사하여 사용하시면 됩니다.

예시)
  • 中文 을 입력하시려면 zhongwen을 입력하시고 space를누르시면됩니다.
  • 北京 을 입력하시려면 beijing을 입력하시고 space를 누르시면 됩니다.
닫기
    인기검색어 순위 펼치기

    RISS 인기검색어

      GAMES OF POLITICAL CHANGE: REFORM-MONGERING IN THE SOVIET UNION, SOUTH AFRICA, AND JAPAN (REFORM, LEADERSHIP).

      한글로보기

      https://www.riss.kr/link?id=T10540243

      • 0

        상세조회
      • 0

        다운로드
      서지정보 열기
      • 내보내기
      • 내책장담기
      • 공유하기
      • 오류접수

      소속기관이 구독 중이 아닌 경우 오후 4시부터 익일 오전 9시까지 원문보기가 가능합니다.

      부가정보

      다국어 초록 (Multilingual Abstract)

      Politicians often are thought to be motivated primarily by a desire to retain office, designing institutions to that end. Changes to the rules of the political game that prove detrimental to the interests of long-ruling groups therefore are of considerable theoretical significance. Existing explanations of the successful reformer's tactics emphasize either surprise and deception or bargaining to create a coalition for change. The former explains neither how a leader who employs such tactics avoids being ousted by disgruntled followers nor accounts for why some successful reformers have opted for prolonged public discussion of change. The latter is both overly optimistic about the resources available to the reformer and unable to account for cases of reform in which most of the ruling group neither desired change nor had been bought off.
      Missing from existing theories of reform is an appreciation for group dynamics. I argue that the reformer can use these dynamics to his advantage in three ways. First, right after assuming the leadership, the reformer can signal his competence by making a decision his colleagues disagree with but which turns out to be in the interests of the ruling group. By demonstrating trustworthiness, the leader may convince colleagues to support reform despite their strong reservations. Second, during the discussion of change, the leader can attempt to coordinate support for a plan by persuading colleagues that other options are worse. Finally, when a vote on reform is held, the leader can exacerbate the collective action problem of opponents by buying off members of the ruling group's inner circle.
      Reform appears most difficult when attempted in a polity long dominated by one party. Comparing successful electoral reform in Japan, the Soviet Union, and South Africa with earlier, less successful, attempts in those countries, reveals how it can come about under the most hostile circumstances. This provides a basis for analyzing less arduous types of change, leading to conclusions about the tactical desiderata of reform in various environments.
      번역하기

      Politicians often are thought to be motivated primarily by a desire to retain office, designing institutions to that end. Changes to the rules of the political game that prove detrimental to the interests of long-ruling groups therefore are of consi...

      Politicians often are thought to be motivated primarily by a desire to retain office, designing institutions to that end. Changes to the rules of the political game that prove detrimental to the interests of long-ruling groups therefore are of considerable theoretical significance. Existing explanations of the successful reformer's tactics emphasize either surprise and deception or bargaining to create a coalition for change. The former explains neither how a leader who employs such tactics avoids being ousted by disgruntled followers nor accounts for why some successful reformers have opted for prolonged public discussion of change. The latter is both overly optimistic about the resources available to the reformer and unable to account for cases of reform in which most of the ruling group neither desired change nor had been bought off.
      Missing from existing theories of reform is an appreciation for group dynamics. I argue that the reformer can use these dynamics to his advantage in three ways. First, right after assuming the leadership, the reformer can signal his competence by making a decision his colleagues disagree with but which turns out to be in the interests of the ruling group. By demonstrating trustworthiness, the leader may convince colleagues to support reform despite their strong reservations. Second, during the discussion of change, the leader can attempt to coordinate support for a plan by persuading colleagues that other options are worse. Finally, when a vote on reform is held, the leader can exacerbate the collective action problem of opponents by buying off members of the ruling group's inner circle.
      Reform appears most difficult when attempted in a polity long dominated by one party. Comparing successful electoral reform in Japan, the Soviet Union, and South Africa with earlier, less successful, attempts in those countries, reveals how it can come about under the most hostile circumstances. This provides a basis for analyzing less arduous types of change, leading to conclusions about the tactical desiderata of reform in various environments.

      더보기

      분석정보

      View

      상세정보조회

      0

      Usage

      원문다운로드

      0

      대출신청

      0

      복사신청

      0

      EDDS신청

      0

      동일 주제 내 활용도 TOP

      더보기

      주제

      연도별 연구동향

      연도별 활용동향

      연관논문

      연구자 네트워크맵

      공동연구자 (7)

      유사연구자 (20) 활용도상위20명

      이 자료와 함께 이용한 RISS 자료

      나만을 위한 추천자료

      해외이동버튼