RISS 학술연구정보서비스

검색
다국어 입력

http://chineseinput.net/에서 pinyin(병음)방식으로 중국어를 변환할 수 있습니다.

변환된 중국어를 복사하여 사용하시면 됩니다.

예시)
  • 中文 을 입력하시려면 zhongwen을 입력하시고 space를누르시면됩니다.
  • 北京 을 입력하시려면 beijing을 입력하시고 space를 누르시면 됩니다.
닫기
    인기검색어 순위 펼치기

    RISS 인기검색어

      企業刑事責任에 대한 比較法的 연구  :  특히 監督責任에 관한 독일과 일본의 판례에 대한 비교연구 = Corporate Criminal Liability from a Comparative Point of View

      한글로보기

      https://www.riss.kr/link?id=A45021912

      • 0

        상세조회
      • 0

        다운로드
      서지정보 열기
      • 내보내기
      • 내책장담기
      • 공유하기
      • 오류접수

      부가정보

      다국어 초록 (Multilingual Abstract)

      Each State Party undertakes to impose penal sanctions on persons who participate in illegal acts committed by or on behalf of corporate entities. Whether corporate entities can be penalized, civilly or criminally, varies among nations. In some nations, corporate entities can be penalized for engaging in environmental crimes. This raises an issue of whether a corporation may be penalized for the activities of its personnel or agents, despite the absence of an overt act on the corporation's behalf. At minimum in nearly all nations, the director, officer, or agent's actions must be within the scope of their employment. Furthermore, there usually must be evidence that the unlawful activities were directed by or with the consent of a senior corporate official and that the direction or consent was given within the scope of that official's authority. Here, the criminal liability of enterprises will be discussed firstly in connection with the criminal liability of individual officers or employees, and secondly in the context of the enterprise as such.
      1. Activities in corporate bodies are typically the result of many interlocked decisions, with a tendency for wide delegation of responsibilities. As a result, where there is "organizational wrongdoing" a criminal system based upon personal fault has difficulties identifying and successfully prosecuting the individual person's responsible. This can lead to an "organized irresponsibility"of individual employees. Therefore, as to perpetrators, both statutory and case law are in the process of extending individual criminal liability especially in the area of entrepreneurial activity. What is the theoretical basis of the criminal liability of corporate officers who in fact are regarded as "responsible persons"? In this case, the vicarious criminal liability of a director, a representative and a manager is avoided because the doctrine of a criminal responsibility is increasingly emphasized. They are to be punished, only when they themselves commit an alleged crime.
      In general, there are now three approaches: (a) The basis of liability of corporate officers may be a corporate criminal act by them within their knowledge and control even if the individual has not performed the unlawful act, at least when such individual ordered or authorized the activity. (b) A broader basis of liability may apply to situations where the corporate officer knows of a subordinate's unlawful activity and does nothing to prevent it. If the corporate officer stands in a position of responsibility over the act in question, liability may be predicated on the failure of the corporate officer to adequately supervise subordinates. (c) A still broader basis of liability is similar to strict liability: the corporate officer may be liable even without evidence of the officer's direct participation or acquiescence in a subordinate's unlawful behavior if the corporate officer holds a responsible position. Only an officer who exercises a high degree of care in attempting to prevent the illegal activity will avoid liability. Approach (a) can be reached by the traditional criminal theory of alders and abettors, but approach (b) or (c) is beyond the reach of this traditional theory. The international trend is to reduce the requirements for intentional behavior when dealing with industrial perpetrators, to create a presumption of intent or to change the burden of proof (approach (b) or (c)).
      Faced with the above-mentioned difficulties as "organizational wrong-doing" or "organized irresponsibility", it is not surprising that, in many countries, adherence to the traditional principle that criminal liability requires personal fault (approach (a)) is being sacrificed in an effort to secure greater environmental protection.
      2. When a corporate behavior has been determined to constitute a crime, it is possible to punish not only an individual perpetrator but also an enterprise itself. Several ways of punishing the enterprise itself exist. In the United States, for example, sanctions include putting the corporation in the custody of a U.S. Marshall, requiring reforms of operations, forcing community service by the corporation and/or individuals, fining, imposing substantial restitution, and providing notice to victims. Punishments can be cumulative. In the case of fining, the estimation of the illegal gains is not admitted generally, but in some countries there are special regulations where such estimation is deemed necessary. For example, in the case of surcharge in the Japanese Antimonopoly Act, the law can deprive illegal gains through imposing a certain rate of the turn over of the enterprise with a clear numerical formula.If national law does not permit corporate culpability,then the implementing legislation should reflect that limitation. However, worldwide there is a tendency to attribute responsibility on an impersonal basis. Even in states that have traditionally adhered to the principle of societas delinquere non potest (enterprises cannot be criminal) Other countries adhere formally to the principle that an enterprise cannot be criminal, but there is a growing tendency toward imposing criminal liability on enterprises.they have looked for ways to impose non-criminal sanctions on those enterprises.
      3. However, in countries like Korea or Japan, the difficulty is not in imposing criminal penalties against the enterprise itself, but rather, in the determination of personal fault. For example, the Korean legislature provides as does the Japanese that a corporate entity is imputed liability if its representative or agent commits a crime under its implementing legislation. According to this provision, however, one should prove who in fact violated the alleged regulation, because that provision requires only that an individual perpetrator acted illegally. Therefore, to prove the illegal conduct of an individual perpetrator is a necessary condition to punish an enterprise. It often happens that the individual perpetrator is difficult to find, especially in the case where the enterprise is a large organization. After the individual perpetrator has been found, it needs to be proved that the conduct of the enterprise is somehow negligent. That is: the enterprise did not meet the duty of care to keep the employee from committing a crime. This omission constitutes a crime of the enterprise. In order to solve this difficulty of evidence, the Korean judiciary has adopted the co-called theory of fault-presumption that allows for finding that a supervisorial duty has been violated within a certain circle of persons. This idea reflects the present difficulty of punishing a large and complicated organization, but has met strong criticism because of the doctrine of guilt ("Schuldprinzip") recognized by the Korean Constitution. As Heine offers, "guilt", as the specific responsibility of the enterprise, should be understood in the sense that the material disposition of the firm prevented it from making legal coordination and reorganization decisions and allowed defective risk management with serious socially detrimental effects to prevail. Faulty decisions over time replace individual guilt.
      번역하기

      Each State Party undertakes to impose penal sanctions on persons who participate in illegal acts committed by or on behalf of corporate entities. Whether corporate entities can be penalized, civilly or criminally, varies among nations. In some nations...

      Each State Party undertakes to impose penal sanctions on persons who participate in illegal acts committed by or on behalf of corporate entities. Whether corporate entities can be penalized, civilly or criminally, varies among nations. In some nations, corporate entities can be penalized for engaging in environmental crimes. This raises an issue of whether a corporation may be penalized for the activities of its personnel or agents, despite the absence of an overt act on the corporation's behalf. At minimum in nearly all nations, the director, officer, or agent's actions must be within the scope of their employment. Furthermore, there usually must be evidence that the unlawful activities were directed by or with the consent of a senior corporate official and that the direction or consent was given within the scope of that official's authority. Here, the criminal liability of enterprises will be discussed firstly in connection with the criminal liability of individual officers or employees, and secondly in the context of the enterprise as such.
      1. Activities in corporate bodies are typically the result of many interlocked decisions, with a tendency for wide delegation of responsibilities. As a result, where there is "organizational wrongdoing" a criminal system based upon personal fault has difficulties identifying and successfully prosecuting the individual person's responsible. This can lead to an "organized irresponsibility"of individual employees. Therefore, as to perpetrators, both statutory and case law are in the process of extending individual criminal liability especially in the area of entrepreneurial activity. What is the theoretical basis of the criminal liability of corporate officers who in fact are regarded as "responsible persons"? In this case, the vicarious criminal liability of a director, a representative and a manager is avoided because the doctrine of a criminal responsibility is increasingly emphasized. They are to be punished, only when they themselves commit an alleged crime.
      In general, there are now three approaches: (a) The basis of liability of corporate officers may be a corporate criminal act by them within their knowledge and control even if the individual has not performed the unlawful act, at least when such individual ordered or authorized the activity. (b) A broader basis of liability may apply to situations where the corporate officer knows of a subordinate's unlawful activity and does nothing to prevent it. If the corporate officer stands in a position of responsibility over the act in question, liability may be predicated on the failure of the corporate officer to adequately supervise subordinates. (c) A still broader basis of liability is similar to strict liability: the corporate officer may be liable even without evidence of the officer's direct participation or acquiescence in a subordinate's unlawful behavior if the corporate officer holds a responsible position. Only an officer who exercises a high degree of care in attempting to prevent the illegal activity will avoid liability. Approach (a) can be reached by the traditional criminal theory of alders and abettors, but approach (b) or (c) is beyond the reach of this traditional theory. The international trend is to reduce the requirements for intentional behavior when dealing with industrial perpetrators, to create a presumption of intent or to change the burden of proof (approach (b) or (c)).
      Faced with the above-mentioned difficulties as "organizational wrong-doing" or "organized irresponsibility", it is not surprising that, in many countries, adherence to the traditional principle that criminal liability requires personal fault (approach (a)) is being sacrificed in an effort to secure greater environmental protection.
      2. When a corporate behavior has been determined to constitute a crime, it is possible to punish not only an individual perpetrator but also an enterprise itself. Several ways of punishing the enterprise itself exist. In the United States, for example, sanctions include putting the corporation in the custody of a U.S. Marshall, requiring reforms of operations, forcing community service by the corporation and/or individuals, fining, imposing substantial restitution, and providing notice to victims. Punishments can be cumulative. In the case of fining, the estimation of the illegal gains is not admitted generally, but in some countries there are special regulations where such estimation is deemed necessary. For example, in the case of surcharge in the Japanese Antimonopoly Act, the law can deprive illegal gains through imposing a certain rate of the turn over of the enterprise with a clear numerical formula.If national law does not permit corporate culpability,then the implementing legislation should reflect that limitation. However, worldwide there is a tendency to attribute responsibility on an impersonal basis. Even in states that have traditionally adhered to the principle of societas delinquere non potest (enterprises cannot be criminal) Other countries adhere formally to the principle that an enterprise cannot be criminal, but there is a growing tendency toward imposing criminal liability on enterprises.they have looked for ways to impose non-criminal sanctions on those enterprises.
      3. However, in countries like Korea or Japan, the difficulty is not in imposing criminal penalties against the enterprise itself, but rather, in the determination of personal fault. For example, the Korean legislature provides as does the Japanese that a corporate entity is imputed liability if its representative or agent commits a crime under its implementing legislation. According to this provision, however, one should prove who in fact violated the alleged regulation, because that provision requires only that an individual perpetrator acted illegally. Therefore, to prove the illegal conduct of an individual perpetrator is a necessary condition to punish an enterprise. It often happens that the individual perpetrator is difficult to find, especially in the case where the enterprise is a large organization. After the individual perpetrator has been found, it needs to be proved that the conduct of the enterprise is somehow negligent. That is: the enterprise did not meet the duty of care to keep the employee from committing a crime. This omission constitutes a crime of the enterprise. In order to solve this difficulty of evidence, the Korean judiciary has adopted the co-called theory of fault-presumption that allows for finding that a supervisorial duty has been violated within a certain circle of persons. This idea reflects the present difficulty of punishing a large and complicated organization, but has met strong criticism because of the doctrine of guilt ("Schuldprinzip") recognized by the Korean Constitution. As Heine offers, "guilt", as the specific responsibility of the enterprise, should be understood in the sense that the material disposition of the firm prevented it from making legal coordination and reorganization decisions and allowed defective risk management with serious socially detrimental effects to prevail. Faulty decisions over time replace individual guilt.

      더보기

      목차 (Table of Contents)

      • Ⅰ. 서론
      • 1. 皮革保護用 噴霧器-判決과 이른바 "탑다운(Top-Down) 考察方式"
      • 2. 本製保護劑事件과 企業刑法의 發展
      • Ⅱ. 독일의 監督責任에 관한 判例의 검토
      • Ⅲ. 일본의 監督責任에 관한 판례
      • Ⅰ. 서론
      • 1. 皮革保護用 噴霧器-判決과 이른바 "탑다운(Top-Down) 考察方式"
      • 2. 本製保護劑事件과 企業刑法의 發展
      • Ⅱ. 독일의 監督責任에 관한 判例의 검토
      • Ⅲ. 일본의 監督責任에 관한 판례
      • 1. 日本의 大型事故에 관한 過失犯判例의 흐름
      • 2. 事故의 諸類型과 過失犯理論의 展開
      • 3. 管理監督過失論의 展開
      • 4. 管理監督過失論의 理論的·刑事政策的 課題
      • 5. 일본의 管理監督責任論의 배경으로서의 過失犯理論의 경향
      • Ⅳ. 비교법적 결론: 企業刑事責任으로서의 監督責任論의 理論的 展開
      • 1. 日本과 獨逸의 상반된 接近方法에 대한 간략한 比較法的 考察과 私見
      더보기

      동일학술지(권/호) 다른 논문

      동일학술지 더보기

      더보기

      분석정보

      View

      상세정보조회

      0

      Usage

      원문다운로드

      0

      대출신청

      0

      복사신청

      0

      EDDS신청

      0

      동일 주제 내 활용도 TOP

      더보기

      주제

      연도별 연구동향

      연도별 활용동향

      연관논문

      연구자 네트워크맵

      공동연구자 (7)

      유사연구자 (20) 활용도상위20명

      이 자료와 함께 이용한 RISS 자료

      나만을 위한 추천자료

      해외이동버튼